Picture of author.

Adam Smith (1) (1723–1790)

Autor(a) de Compendio da obra da riqueza das nações

Para outros autores com o nome Adam Smith, ver a página de desambiguação.

83+ Works 11,221 Membros 71 Críticas 16 Favorited

About the Author

Adam Smith (1723-1790) was a key figure in the Scottish Enlightenment. Born in Scotland and educated at Glasgow and Oxford universities, he was a professor of logic and later chair of moral philosophy at Glasgow University. Smith wrote two major classics, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) and mostrar mais The Wealth of Nations (1776), earning him a reputation as "the Father of Economics." mostrar menos
Image credit: Wikipedia

Séries

Obras por Adam Smith

The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) 1,538 exemplares
Wealth of Nations (selections) (1993) 253 exemplares
The Invisible Hand (2008) 160 exemplares
Lectures on Jurisprudence (1976) 131 exemplares
Essays on Philosophical Subjects (1795) 128 exemplares
The Essential Adam Smith (1986) 116 exemplares
Correspondence of Adam Smith (1977) 69 exemplares
The Wisdom of Adam Smith (1976) 47 exemplares
Wealth of Nations 3 exemplares
Vive l'Etat ! (2012) 3 exemplares
Folkens välstånd 2 exemplares
Poverty and wealth (1982) 1 exemplar
Economistas Políticos (2001) 1 exemplar
Essays 1 exemplar
Economia dei sentimenti (2011) 1 exemplar
Os Economistas 1 exemplar
RIQUEZA DE LAS NACIONES.,LA (2002) 1 exemplar
Essay on colonies 1 exemplar
Mano invisible, La (2013) 1 exemplar

Associated Works

An Enquiry Concerning Human Understanding (1748) — Contribuidor, algumas edições3,863 exemplares
The Crowd: A Study of the Popular Mind (1895) — Introdução, algumas edições983 exemplares
Taking Sides: Clashing Views in Business Ethics and Society (1990) — Contribuidor, algumas edições72 exemplares
The Grim Reader: Writings on Death, Dying, and Living On (1997) — Contribuidor — 61 exemplares
Classics of Modern Political Theory : Machiavelli to Mill (1996) — Contribuidor — 49 exemplares
British Moralists 1650-1800, Vol. 1 Hobbes-Gay (1969) — Contribuidor — 20 exemplares
British Moralists 1650-1800, Vol. 2 Hume-Bentham and Index (1991) — Contribuidor — 18 exemplares

Etiquetado

Conhecimento Comum

Membros

Críticas

An exposition relying on common sense moral realism to explore why people maintain the moral frameworks and structures they do. Smith seems to rely heavily on the premise that sympathy/empathy is a primary driver for the kind of ways people behave.

That's a very short summary of a much longer and expansive presentation. Much of the time I was not quite really sure what I was reading. There's not much appeal to any other kind of authority other than what an 18th century Scotsman who traveled around the United Kingdom and France and heard some stories about America would accept based on his experience. In this respect the difference between the past and present proves quite vast; one comes to realize quickly how much of what we today accept and believe about people and their behaviors should have some kind of basis in psychiatry, sociology, and results from experiments and studies in those domains. Granted, neither existed in the middle of the 18th century, and so that's not exactly Smith's fault.

Thus, as a relic of a former age and part of the heritage upon which later belief systems were built, this volume has value. Just accepting his conclusions based on his premises would, however, prove woefully insufficient today.
… (mais)
 
Assinalado
deusvitae | 12 outras críticas | May 4, 2024 |
Theory of Moral Sentiments by Adam Smith

BIBLIOGRAPHIC DETAILS
-PRINT: COPYRIGHT: (1759) 10/3/2009 ; ISBN979-8767293278; PUBLISHER: Independently published; LENGTH: 311 pages) [Info from Amazon]
-DIGITAL: COPYRIGHT: (1759) 11/14/2021 ; ISBN: 1090273142; PUBLISHER: Uplifting Publications; LENGTH: 440 pages; 563 KB) [Info from Amazon]
*AUDIO: COPYRIGHT: (1759) 7/30/2020; PUBLISHER: Author’s Republic; LENGTH: 16 hours (approx.); Unabridged. [Info from Libby-LAPL--the primary version I consumed-Goodreads doesn't list this version]
(Film: No).

SERIES
No

SUMMARY/ EVALUATION:
-SELECTION: I learned of this publication when reading “Wealth of Nations”. This was said to be a foundation for that.
-ABOUT: Descriptions of sympathy, passions, vices, strengths, gaining society’s approval. . There are 188 (give or take one or two) instances of “approbation” and 40 (give or take one or two) instances of “disapprobation”. The approval of one’s fellow man seems to be the primary theme.
-LIKED: At some point, this reminded me a little of “Emotional Intelligence”. Smith references many philosophers, both ancient and what would have been current for him. Of interest is that he does not refer to God, but seems to assign a feminine Director of Nature that position-
-DISLIKED: The narration was sometimes difficult to follow--an occasional slur of a word, an occasional intonation that sounded disconnected from the subject, by either being assigned to the sentence before or the sentence after the one it seemed it should belong to, but I can’t imagine this was an easy work to read. It was long, at times seeming repetitive-or unnecessarily so.
-OVERALL: Enjoyed. I’m a novice to philosophy so this was always interesting but at times incomprehensible.

AUTHOR: Adam Smith: “Adam Smith FRSA (baptised 16 June [O.S. 5 June] 1723[5] – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish[a] economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the thinking of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment.[7] Seen by some as "The Father of Economics"[8] or "The Father of Capitalism",[9] he wrote two classic works, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) and An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776). The latter, often abbreviated as The Wealth of Nations, is considered his magnum opus and the first modern work that treats economics as a comprehensive system and as an academic discipline. Smith refuses to explain the distribution of wealth and power in terms of God's will and instead appeals to natural, political, social, economic and technological factors and the interactions between them. Among other economic theories, the work introduced Smith's idea of absolute advantage.[10]
Smith studied social philosophy at the University of Glasgow and at Balliol College, Oxford, where he was one of the first students to benefit from scholarships set up by fellow Scot John Snell. After graduating, he delivered a successful series of public lectures at the University of Edinburgh,[11] leading him to collaborate with David Hume during the Scottish Enlightenment. Smith obtained a professorship at Glasgow, teaching moral philosophy and during this time, wrote and published The Theory of Moral Sentiments. In his later life, he took a tutoring position that allowed him to travel throughout Europe, where he met other intellectual leaders of his day.” [ ___Amazon.com ]

NARRATOR: John Klickman: [No bio info found online.]

GENRE: Nonfiction; Philosophy

LOCATIONS: NA

TIME FRAME 1759

SUBJECTS: Approbation, sympathy, empathy, morality, honesty, deceit, philosophy; casuistry; psychology; sociology; history;

SAMPLE QUOTATION: From “Of the Manner in Which Different Authors Have Treated of the Practical Rules of Morality”
“Frankness and openness conciliate confidence. We trust the man who seems willing to trust us. We see clearly, we think, the road by which he means to conduct us, and we abandon ourselves with pleasure to his guidance and direction. Reserve and concealment, on the contrary, call forth diffidence. We are afraid to follow the man who is going we do not know where. The great pleasure of conversation and society, besides, arises from a certain correspondence of sentiments and opinions, from a certain harmony of minds, which, like so many musical, instruments coincide and keep time with one another. But this most delightful harmony cannot be obtained unless there is a free communication of sentiments and opinions. We all desire, upon this account, to feel how each other is affected, to penetrate into each other’s bosoms, and to observe the sentiments and affections which really subsist there. The man who indulges us in this natural passion, who invites us into his heart, who, as it were, sets open the gates of his breast to us, seems to exercise a species of hospitality more delightful than any other. No man, who is in ordinary good temper, can fail of pleasing, if he has the courage to utter his real sentiments as he feels them, and because he feels them. It is this unreserved sincerity which renders even the prattle of a child agreeable. How weak and imperfect soever the views of the open-hearted, we take pleasure to enter into them, and endeavour, as much as we can, to bring down our own understanding to the level of their capacities, and to regard every subject in the particular light in which they appear to have considered it. This passion to discover the real sentiments of others is naturally so strong, that it often degenerates into a troublesome and impertinent curiosity to pry into those secrets of our neighbours which they have very justifiable reasons for concealing; and upon many occasions it requires prudence and a strong sense of propriety to govern this, as well as all the other passions of human nature, and to reduce it to that pitch which any impartial spectator can approve of. To disappoint this curiosity, however, when it is kept within proper bounds, and aims at nothing which there can be any just reason for concealing, is equally disagreeable in its turn. The man who eludes our most innocent questions, who gives no satisfaction to our most inoffensive inquiries, who plainly wraps himself up in impenetrable obscurity, seems, as it were, to build a wall about his breast. We run forward to get within it with all the eagerness of harmless curiosity, and feel ourselves all at once pushed back with the rudest and most offensive violence.

The man of reserve and concealment, though seldom a very amiable character, is not disrespected or despised. He seems to feel coldly towards us, and we feel as coldly towards him; he is not much praised or beloved, but he is as little hated or blamed. He very seldom, however, has occasion to repent of his caution, and is generally disposed rather to value himself upon the prudence of his reserve. Though his conduct, therefore, may have been very faulty, and sometimes even hurtful, he can very seldom be disposed to lay his case before the casuists, or to fancy that he has any occasion for their acquittal or approbation.

It is not always so with the man who, from false information, from inadvertency, from precipitancy and rashness, has involuntarily deceived. Though it should be in a matter of little consequence, in telling a piece of common news, for example, if he is a real lover of truth, he is ashamed of his own carelessness, and never fails to embrace the first opportunity of making the fullest acknowledgments. If it is in a matter of some consequence, his contrition is still greater; and if any unlucky or fatal consequence has followed from his misinformation, he can scarce ever forgive himself. Though not guilty, he feels himself to be in the highest degree what the ancients called piacular, and is anxious and eager to make every sort of atonement in his power. Such a person might frequently be disposed to lay his case before the casuists, who have in general been very favourable to him, and though they have sometimes justly condemned him for rashness, they have universally acquitted him of the ignominy of falsehood.

But the man who had the most frequent occasion to consult them was the man of equivocation and mental reservation, the man who seriously and deliberately meant to deceive, but who, at the same time, wished to flatter himself that he had really told the truth. With him they have dealt variously. When they approved very much of the motives of his deceit, they have sometimes acquitted him, though, to do them justice, they have in general, and much more frequently condemned him.

The chief subjects of the works of the casuists, therefore, were the conscientious regard that is due to the rules of justice; how far we ought to respect the life and property of our neighbour; the duty of restitution; the laws of chastity and modesty, and wherein consisted what in their language are called the sins of concupiscence; the rules of veracity, and the obligation of oaths, promises, and contracts of all kinds.

It may be said in general of the works of the casuists, that they attempted, to no purpose, to direct, by precise rules, what it belongs to feeling and sentiment only to judge of. How is it possible to ascertain by rules the exact point at which, in every case, a delicate sense of justice begins to run into a frivolous and weak scrupulosity of conscience? When it is that secrecy and reserve begin to grow into dissimulation? How far an agreeable irony may be carried, and at what precise point it begins to degenerate into a detestable lie? What is the highest pitch of freedom and ease of behaviour which can be regarded as graceful and becoming, and when it is that it first begins to run into a negligent and thoughtless licentiousness? With regard to all such matters, what would hold good in any one case would scarce do so exactly in any other, and what constitutes the propriety and happiness of behaviour varies in every case with the smallest variety of situation. Books of casuistry, therefore, are generally as useless as they are commonly tiresome. They could be of little use to one who should consult them upon occasion, even supposing their decisions to be just; because, notwithstanding the multitude of cases collected in them, yet, upon account of the still greater variety of possible circumstances, it is a chance if, among all those cases, there be found one exactly parallel to that under consideration. One who is really anxious to do his duty, must be very weak if he can imagine that he has much occasion for them; and with regard to one who is negligent of it, the style of those writings is not such as is likely to awaken him to more attention. None of them tend to animate us to what is generous and noble. None of them tend to soften us to what is gentle and humane. Many of them, on the contrary, tend rather to teach us to chicane with our own consciences, and, by their vain subtilties, serve to authorize innumerable evasive refinements with regard to the most essential articles of our duty. That frivolous accuracy which they attempted to introduce into subjects which do not admit of it, almost necessarily betrayed them into those dangerous errors, and at the same time rendered their works dry and disagreeable, abounding in abtruse and metaphysical distinctions, but incapable of exciting in the heart any of those emotions which it is the principal use of books of morality to excite.”

RATING: 3.5 stars. As always, this reflects my understanding more than the author’s writing.

STARTED-FINISHED 6/19/23 - 7/2/23

… (mais)
 
Assinalado
TraSea | 12 outras críticas | Apr 29, 2024 |
A great book, but not for everyone. Amazing insights which are still as valid today as 1775 when the book was written.

Very detailed, great analysis and I really learned a lot from this book. Hard to read in sections, as it is written in very verbose, antiquated English.

I would recommend it if you are interested in Economics and want to gain a perspective from first principles.
 
Assinalado
rendier | 44 outras críticas | Jan 25, 2024 |
Rústica.
Buen estado
 
Assinalado
Accitanus | 1 outra crítica | Nov 17, 2023 |

Listas

Prémios

You May Also Like

Associated Authors

Toby Haynes Director
Matthew Fox Illustrator
George Whitefield Contributor
Voltaire Contributor
François Quesnai Contributor
Joseph Butler Contributor
John Toland Contributor
Samuel Johnson Contributor
Edward Gibbon Contributor
David Hume Contributor
Henry Fielding Contributor
Bryan Elsley Creator
Delilah S. Dawson Contributor
Dan Jackson Contributor
Jared Cullum Contributor
Katie Cook Contributor
Roger Langridge Contributor
Heather Breckel Contributor
Curry Ross Contributor
Jim Campbell Contributor
Pius Bak Contributor
Sas Milledge Contributor
Henry J. Cobb Contributor
Howard Kistler Contributor
Kelly Nall Contributor
Joseph Zakszewski Contributor
James Eisert Contributor
David L. Pulver Contributor
Chris Warden Contributor
Greg Miller Contributor
Stefan Jones Contributor
Simon Nye Writer
Murray Gold Composer
Charles Dickens Original story
John Lunn Composer
Rick Hershey Illustrator
Phil Reed Designer
William McAusland Illustrator
Robert B. Reich Introduction
Ludwig Von Mises Introduction
Alan B. Krueger Introduction
Edwin R.A. Seligman Introduction
Derek Kirk Kim Cover artist
Jeff Stokely Cover artist
Ryan Sook Cover artist

Estatísticas

Obras
83
Also by
9
Membros
11,221
Popularidade
#2,102
Avaliação
3.9
Críticas
71
ISBN
698
Línguas
25
Marcado como favorito
16

Tabelas & Gráficos